0:33 | Intro. [Recording date: May 15, 2015.] Russ: Now, you argue that prudence requires doing something about the growing concentration of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere. Give us an overview of what you see as the big-picture version of the problem: why action is a good idea, and in particular, what's the ideal of what we ought to do about it? Guest: Well, in the book and in other contexts, I, we have argued that the most important single way to view the economics of climate change is primarily as a problem of risk management. You can't--we don't know what's going to happen. It's highly uncertain what the outcome is going to be on temperatures, on weather patterns, and so forth. And instead of trying to pretend that it's deterministic by taking average values, we really need to look at the whole probability distribution of outcomes. And when we do that, we see that there is an uncomfortable amount of probability--small but it's not negligible--that there will be really very bad outcomes: that temperatures really could go up a great deal with a small probability, but not small enough to comfort us. So, what we should be doing, the way we should be thinking about this is more like a problem of buying insurance against terrible outcomes than it is to lower the average of such outcomes. Russ: So, this is, as you say in the book, a fat-tail problem, in your mind, what Nassim Taleb has talked about on the program with respect to finance. And also he has argued with respect to both GMOs (genetically modified organisms) and climate change--that there's such a catastrophic risk, a catastrophic outcome of a low probability, but that probability is not low enough that we can ignore it. Is that a good way to summarize it? Guest: Yes, it is. Russ: Let's talk about why you think it's a fat tail rather than an unlikelihood. We've had, I think--correct me if I'm wrong--0.8 degrees of Celsius warming, which is 1.4 Fahrenheit, above pre-industrial times. What is the Black Swan? What's the catastrophic outcome that you think we should worry about? And what would the consequences be? Guest: Any degree Centigrade, we probably can and we are living with it. It's going to go up--if there were no more carbon dioxide emitted, what's in the pipeline already is going to cause temperatures to go above 0.8 degrees Centigrade. But in these low-ish ranges, say, less than 2 degrees Centigrade, we have some more confidence that we can cope with the problem. When carbon dioxide concentrations, greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere get high enough, then you really might get into the 6-degree or 4-degree range. And we did, in the book, some fairly simple calculations, but there were calculations, that--I'll throw some numbers in here. Before the Industrial Revolution, the level of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere was 280 parts per million. And it had hardly ever been above 280 parts per million in 800,000 years. We know that 800,000 years from arctic ice cores. And it stands to reason--we've been in this period of glacial advances and retreats for about 3 million[?] years, so this is probably at the upper end of what parts per million of carbon dioxide and greenhouse gases were for the last 3 million years or so. Now we are up to about 440 parts per million of carbon dioxide equivalent gases. That's an increase of 50% over what was the highest for the last 3 million years at least. When you ask, 'What is going to happen with 440 parts per million?' you are looking at something called, a famous acronym in climate change, something called Climate Sensitivity. And that is an iconic number that tells us the eventual temperature change that goes along with a greenhouse gas concentration. It's a probability distribution. So this essential thing about what will be the temperature response to 440-560 is an answer that has a distribution. And the climate sensitivity is the temperature change for a doubling of carbon dioxide. So, we're not there yet. But it's almost sure that we'll reach at least that, at least 560 parts per million. For the last 35 years, the uncertainty around this climate sensitivity, this temperature response, has not much changed. Thirty five years ago in some of the first early engineering studies it was stated that it's likely between 1.5 degree centigrade and 3.5 degree centigrade--oh, I'm sorry--it's likely between 1.5 degrees centigrade and 4.5 degrees centigrade. That's a pretty wide range, 1.5-4.5 degrees centigrade. And that's in the latest IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) report from last year, it gives that same range. So that, what's happened, seemingly, is that although there has been much, much more research into climate change, and many, many more models and observations, we must be--as we are resolving some of the uncertainty about something like climate sensitivity, new forms of uncertainty are emerging. So there's other things that we hadn't counted on. Okay, so this 1 degree centigrade to 4.5 degree centigrade--what we estimated is that if the greenhouse gas concentrations double, the chance of being greater than 4.5 degrees centigrade is around 10%. If greenhouse gas concentrations double, the probability of being greater than 6 degrees centigrade response is around 3%. So this is the bad tail of climate sensitivity, which is symbolic of the bad tail of what the damages could be. And these numbers just seem alarming, with the doubling of CO2, which is almost inevitable, there is a 3% chance of having temperatures greater than, a temperature response greater than 6 degrees. If we go to a concentration of greenhouse gases of 700 parts per million--and that's a number that's thrown around, for example the International Energy Agency, that's their most likely scenario taking account of all the pledges that had been made and so for--their point estimate is that we will reach 700 within a century. If it's at 700, then the probability that the temperature response is greater than 6 degrees centigrade becomes around 10%. So that's what--my best translation into actual numbers of what it means to have a fat tail. Those 8%, 10% probabilities are low--they are unlikely. But they are not nearly so low as to put our minds at ease. And that's what I, we see as the major driving factor in wanting to mitigate carbon dioxide emissions. It's not so much as what happens in the middle so much as what's happening in those bad tails. |
9:54 | Russ: So, the outcome there is so catastrophic, the argument goes, that the fact that it's "only 10%" or only 3% is not comforting. Those are alarmingly large probabilities of a very, very bad event. Guest: Exactly. Russ: Which would be a temperature increase--and just to keep the numbers clean--we're at 440 parts per million in the atmosphere now. Pre-industrial revolution we think is around 280. So that's your point that we are about 50% higher. We expect to get to double the pre-industrial concentration--that's what you said is inevitable. That's 560. If we get something close to double where we are now, we get to 700 and above, and there, you are suggesting that the odds, then, of an at least 6-degree centigrade increase would be 10%. And 6 degrees is considered, something above 6, would be life-altering. So, before we talk about the probabilities of that 700, because I want to come back to that, whether that's a realistic concern, what else goes into that number: What do you think we know--and you conceded many times in the book there are many things we don't know, still--about life on earth at 6 degrees centigrade above the current average. Guest: Lord. For that you'd have to go way back. To find that much carbon dioxide, an increase of that much carbon dioxide or greenhouse gas, that rapidly, so that rapidly, to 700 hasn't been seen for at least 50 million years. Fifty million years ago there was a spike in temperatures that was something like this 4 or 5 degrees; and also there were higher levels of carbon dioxide. So, we really are going way, way back. That would alter--6 degrees centigrade, if that were achieved would alter life on earth as we know it. We're into the fantasy world here in guessing what that would be like. It would completely up-end ecosystems and cause a lot of species to go extinct. I don't know what would happen to humans. I don't see how anyone can know. Maybe we'd be clever enough to figure out how to live underground or something like that. Science has achieved marvelous things. But it somehow wouldn't be at all, I'm guessing, a pleasant existence. And we would miss life on earth as we know it today. You'd have a lot of trouble venturing outside your underground shelter, if we could even survive at all at 700 parts per million. So, again, it was that that first, it was numbers like that that first started to bother and then alarm me about climate change--that you put it in geological, historical perspective, and what we're doing is really tampering with these greenhouse gas levels to an extent, by the time we're done, that hasn't been seen for at least 50 million years. Well, that's a big deal. If there's the amount of uncertainty that IPCC seems to think there is, this incredible range of climate sensitivity between 1.5 and 4.5 degrees centigrade, if there are ranges like that for what the response is, we haven't seen such things since, as I say, 50 million years ago. |
13:56 | Russ: So, I'm going to make an analogy I've made here before, which is: it does remind me a little bit of macroeconomics, which is something I have a similar agnosticism about or sometimes a skepticism. So, in macroeconomics, we're told that there's a theoretical reason to expect that a dollar of government spending financed by debt will have a certain impact on GDP (Gross Domestic Product) or on unemployment; and if it doesn't happen, say, after WWII, as was predicted when government spending shrunk and we were told we were going to have a catastrophic economy, then we say, 'Well, there were other things we didn't anticipate'--and the theory survives. So, what is your thought on the last 15 or 16 years, sometimes called the Pause, where concentrations of carbon dioxide have risen dramatically as China has grown dramatically, the world economy has grown dramatically, and yet the expected temperature increases didn't happen, haven't happened? It's true the world remains hot. But the theory is predicting that it should get a lot hotter. Does that give you any uncertainty about this relationship between greenhouse gases in the atmosphere and temperature and the likelihood that 700 parts per million is going to be 6-plus degrees centigrade hotter than it is now? Guest: With a 10% probability. Well, I think it emphasizes how unsure we are. The models are all pointing in a general direction of the planet heating. But they can't really capture--they certainly can't capture year-to-year changes or even decade-to-decade. The big picture is that--see, if you look at a plot of temperature against time, it's as if we are on a plateau now but that's looking back for 12 years or so. If you look decade by decade, there's an unambiguous increase in temperature. It's indicating we don't know, and maybe the effect is going to be more than 9. But it's not nearly enough years or enough data to undo this thinking that we're handed for pretty high temperature changes. There's things that the models somehow can't seem to model very well, and that are maybe very important: cloud formation--we don't know what's going to happen. That's a huge deal in saying what temperature change will be. None of the models predicted melting of arctic sea ice, which has continued to increase, the melting of arctic sea ice. That was not predicted. And yet the twiddle with the models that try to make them come out with something like that. Russ: [?] that. We're good at twiddling. As econometricians, for example, we know how to do that. Guest: Yeah. But if every time there's some news, you need to revise the model, you're left unsure about the uncertainty in it. Russ: Correct. |
17:27 | Russ: Well, let's move to the one policy change that you talk about quite a bit in the book, and that many economists continue to come back to, which is a tax on carbon. So, you argue that we should put a $40 per ton tax on carbon, to at least begin reducing the rate of increase that we're currently having in CO2 in the atmosphere. Where does that number come from? Or, what's our best way we have to make a stab at that number? The reason I ask that is--we understand something about other types of pollutants and their impacts on health, say, or the economy, we have a measure of the externality at the margin. This is a strange one, because, as you say, in our current existence, we are getting along okay with the 0.8 that we've had. It's not obvious that an extra half a degree should be discouraged. It's a non--the way I think about it is, it's an infra-marginal problem, really. Right? Guest: Yes, I suppose. Russ: So, make a case for $40. Guest: Okay. I can't make a very firm case. And no one can. Russ: Understand. Guest: Like, so much else in this area of climate change, that's a calculation based on a series of models. It's a consortium, as it were, of U.S. government agencies that got together, including the Department of the Interior, the Council of Economic Advisers, the Treasury, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)--they formed a fairly large task force to come up with what the price on carbon that would be used in regulation by the EPA. The Supreme Court said, and mandated, that EPA should take account of carbon dioxide. It's not that they are going to put a $40 tax on carbon--they don't have the power to do that. But in evaluating various new technologies and machinery and various controls, they are using this number. Where did they get it from? Well, the thought experiment is this: You have some given trajectory of carbon dioxide emissions and carbon dioxide concentrations, and then temperatures that go along with that. It might be uncertain, but you have a sort of projected profile of temperatures and damages into the future. Then, you do a thought experiment: via the computer you make there be 1 less ton of carbon dioxide that's emitted this year. That will translate into fractionally lower temperatures in the future, and fractionally lower damages in the future. And then you take these damages, these changed damages, and discount them back to the present, and ask: What is the so-called cost of carbon--which is really the price of carbon that's coming out of the model--that it wants you to impose? They use 3 models, 3 so-called Integrated Assessment Models, IAM. And they got 3 different answers. They just averaged them. And a huge part of the uncertainty about this $40 per ton comes from the discounting aspect. If you discount--because consequences of climate change unfold across centuries and even millennia, and certainly generations, the discount rate you use becomes absolutely critical. And the discount rate they used was 3%. They looked at 2.5% and at 5%. You get very different numbers for 2.5% or for 5%. Or for any change in the discount rate. So, the deficiencies of this, ambiguities of it, are known to those who work in this area. This is not in any sense a hard and firm number. But it's sort of a ballpark estimate that's very sensitive to a bunch of assumptions, including, especially, the discount rate. And that's the number that they came up with after averaging over three models. So that's where that number, $40, comes from. Russ: So, right now, worldwide, you suggest that we subsidize--right now in reality we subsidize carbon in various ways. Which would certainly seem to me, regardless of what you think of climate change, that that would be a good thing to stop. And you point out that that, whether that's a good thing to stop or not, it's a very hard thing to stop politically. But if we reversed that, and stopped subsidizing it and instead taxed it, one question to ask would be: What is the likely cost of that level of taxation on economic growth, or on people living in very poor places that desperately need energy to catch up? You didn't talk much about that in the book. I was a little bit surprised. Do you have any feel for what kind of magnitudes that kind of tax would have on, say, the price of gasoline per gallon? Something that would be more easily related to, as a consumer? Guest: I think $40 per ton of carbon dioxide doesn't affect gasoline that much. I think it will come out to about 4 cents per gallon in the United States where it's already taxed. It would show up for sure in electricity prices. One point I want to make clear is that a difficult point to get across to the public: When the public thinks of a tax of $40 per ton of carbon dioxide, say, they think of that $40 as going somewhere, away from them. It goes into a sinkhole or it's transferred to another country-- Russ: planet-- Guest: or it's transferred--yeah--to the United Nations, or something like that. That's not the case. This tax really represents a country that would be taxing itself on carbon dioxide. And with the receipts that they gather on the carbon dioxide from that weight [?] carbon dioxide, they could do things like relieve more distortionary taxes elsewhere. Because a bunch of calculations show that if you tax--you end up better from a welfare point of view if you tax this bad of carbon dioxide, and relieve taxes on goods, such as labor or capital. So this would allow a refund of $40 per carbon dioxide on going elsewhere into the economy. Russ: In theory. In theory, at least. Guest: Yes. And people have thrown around numbers--there's models, and there's numbers; and some of the models seem to indicate that actually if judiciously done, things [?] words, this could increase national welfare, because you are eliminating or cutting back on distortionary taxes. So, depending upon--the hurt that it does depends on what you do with the internal proceeds of the tax. So, the idea--maybe it's better to call it a price on carbon. The idea is that a country would price carbon, hopefully at $40 per ton; would collect these receipts and use it to offset taxes elsewhere. Or to do other-- Russ: Or to do other good things, if they have good things to do with the money. In general. Guest: That's something that's very hard. We economists have not done a very good job of explaining that--that it's not a tax in the sense that it's going away from you and to some larger entity and disappearing from you. The nation as a whole, it doesn't disappear from the nation. The nation collects it. Russ: Well, it will go away from you if you if you are a relatively heavy user of carbon, in whatever dimension that comes out. So, if you are, like, mail order--if you do a lot of mail order shopping, this is going to increase the cost of jet fuel and other things that are electricity intensive, etc., etc. But the point, the basic point you are making is a very important one. The goal here isn't to make government bigger--although people worry that's what it would do. But the goal of it, at least, would be to reallocate--not reallocate, but alter the price of carbon relative to other goods that are currently just priced to high because of the taxes that are put on them. So that, in theory, could be a welfare-improving tax, at least in theory. |
27:33 | Russ: The other alternative, which you mention, is some kind of cap-and-trade scheme. It seems to me that, given that many of the effects occur at sort of a tipping point of sorts, at, say, 500, 600, maybe 700 parts per million, that ideally--I'm going to emphasize 'ideally'--ideally you would want to put some kind of total cap on global emissions and then allow people to trade those. Allow governments and corporations to trade those, so that the allocation of that a fixed amount was in some sense sufficient. Of course, that would be--if you don't endow people with certain amounts, you can certainly make the argument that poorer countries should get bigger allocations to start with because they are behind, and it would seem to be a very cruel system--as is the tax--to punish them, make it hard for them to catch up. But in theory you could give people an endowment of these rights to emit, allow it to be traded, and then you could make sure it didn't go over 600, or 500, if you knew how to monitor and enforce it, right? Guest: Yes. Some tricky parts in that. First of all the thing you care about is not emissions per se. It's the accumulation of the stock of carbon dioxide that's in the atmosphere. And that becomes a little trickier, how to link that to a cap-and-trade system. Look, a cap and trade system, and a tax or price on carbon, are very similarly related. And within the United States, or within the advanced OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) countries, I'd say, gee it would be great if you could get either one of these meaningfully linked up. When it comes to the entire world, including the developing countries, my own opinion is that a cap and trade system is inferior to this general agreement to put a price on carbon, for several reasons. One is that by putting a price on carbon you are stabilizing the price of energy. It's going to be linked to that price of carbon. If you have a cap and trade system, energy prices could go all over the case, depending on whether you are in a recession or not. And they have gone all over the place, in Europe, and now way below what they were previously. In the United States, cap and trade prices have gone lower than was anticipated. And the public is very averse to these price changes. So, the public doesn't feel comfortable--if the price soared on cap and trade, on a cap and trade mechanism, if the price of energy soared, why, then, people would be accusing Wall Street of manipulating some prices because they [?] the will, make[?] decisions on these cap and trade systems. And it could end up discrediting the whole movement, to put on an economic basis, on a rational economic basis, the control of carbon. So that's one reason. Another thing that bothers me about a cap-and-trade international system is, let's face it, somehow if this were distributed, there are going to be huge flows of billions, maybe trillions of dollars from the United States or advanced countries to China. And I don't think that would be tolerated very well domestically. So--I, myself, favor, for the international solution, an international price or tax on carbon. Also, with a cap and trade system, you are into, right from the beginning, who gets assigned what caps. And a lot of money is riding on that. Russ: That's right. Guest: So you've got to negotiate with n parties somehow. Russ: It's not going to happen. Guest: Yeah. Russ: I want to read a paragraph from the opening of your book. It might be the first paragraph. I can't remember. But I cut and pasted it. It says:Climate change is an urgent problem. But you're fooling yourself if you think getting off of fossil fuels would be simple. It will be one of the most difficult challenges modern civilization has ever faced, and it will require the most sustained, well-managed, globally cooperative effort the human species has ever mounted. Well, 'sustained, well-managed, and globally cooperative'--I can't think of anything that we've ever done that fulfills those adjectives. So, it's a long shot. One nation--a particular nation can put a tax through its own political process on its own carbon emissions. The odds that we will as a globe come together to figure out and solve the problems you are talking about seems to me to be close to zero. Guest: Well, this gets into another point, which is: When does the world sort of wake up? And the pessimistic side of me says it would take the perception of a catastrophe, of a climate change catastrophe, in order to make this be an issue on the grass roots level. Like analogous to the 2008 Recession. Russ: To give it salience. For it to rise to the level of fear and panic on the part of the everyday person, you'd need to see things like there are no vegetables in the grocery store or they are only available on a limited basis because of agricultural change. Right? And then it's too late--probably, as you'd suggest. Guest: That's right. But, the pessimistic part of me says that that makes the perception of the catastrophe not exogenous but endogenous. Because if we go up by another hundred parts per million and there's no terrible outcomes perceived, we'll go up another hundred parts per million. And then another hundred. Until there is this perception on a grass roots level that this is really biting, this is really hurting. Though, then it becomes a question not whether there will be a perceived--it's the perception that's important--a perceived catastrophe, but when that will occur. Yeah, these proposed solutions are all difficult; and cap and trade has some things in its favor over and internationally agreed-upon price of carbon. But I think we got going on the wrong foot when we started down, when we began with this quantity path. Because it's so very, very difficult to get n countries to agree on what their initial reductions ought to be. Everyone wants some leniency in that. Somehow, a uniform price, if we can get everyone to agree on a uniform price and then they--I don't know--vote on it or negotiate what that price is going to be--you are then negotiating with a one-dimensional entity, the price, instead of n-dimensional different caps. And that somehow seems to me to have more promise. But it ain't easy. |
35:41 | Russ: I want to read a somewhat lengthy excerpt from the book that I thought really captured the nature of the problem. And it captures this issue, the one we are talking about now, which is the salience issue--what's at the front of people's minds and the political challenges of dramatic action if it's not at the front of people's minds. And I think that is part of what drives climate scientists crazy, that the rest of us are just kind of like thinking, 'Not much going on here. Why are you yelling at me?' And just as an aside, I think the biggest--of course, this failure to get people excited about it is despite the steady drumbeat by the media which in general are more concerned about it than the average person; movies that suggest it's going to be catastrophic. And I think that one of the reasons it's failed is, Al Gore being a spokesperson for a movement--he's a politician, he's seen as a partisan. And that immediately took about 35% of the population into hostility toward the idea. Whether that was wise or not is a different question. But I think, just an interesting question of why so many smart people are worried about this and so many somewhat smart people are not. There are smart people who are not worried about it; we've had some of them on the program; we may hear from them again. But it's an interesting political question of how do you get people to worry about a problem that's in the future. And you have a nice metaphor that captures that. And it also captures the uncertainty. So let me read it:If a civilization-as-we-know-it altering asteroid hurtling toward Earth, scheduled to hit a decade hence, and it had say a 5 percent chance of striking the planet, we would surely pull out all the stops to try to deflect its path.
If we knew that same asteroid were hurtling toward Earth a century hence, we may spend a few more years arguing about the precise course of action, but here's what we wouldn't do: We wouldn't say that we should be able to solve the problem in at most a decade, so we can just sit back and relax for another 90 years. Nor would we try to bank on the fact that technologies will be that much better in 90 years, so we can probably do nothing for 91 or 92 years and we'd still be fine. </br/>We'd act, and soon. Never mind that technologies will be getting better in the next 90 years, and never mind that we may find out more about the asteroid's precise path over the next 90 years that may be able to tell us that the chance of it hitting Earth is "only" 4 percent rather than the 5 percent we'd assumed all along. So, I don't know about that, actually. When I read that--you gave that analogy to make a point. I guess the question would be: I'd want to know what pulling out all the stops would do to life here on earth. It's true that if there's a 5% chance that life on earth is going to be altered by the impact of this asteroid 100 years from now, I'd be worried about it. I'd think, 'Yeah, we should do something now.' But would I pull out all the stops? Would I devote 50% of world GDP, 30% of world GDP, to create the technology that's going to allow us to destroy it or deflect it? I might want to wait a little bit. I might want to invest in those technologies now but not to solve the problem in 10 years. And I'd want to think about what the scope of it would be. But if it meant impoverishing people, say, terribly, I'd be loathe to attack the problem now. I would be tempted to wait. Or do you think I'm wrong? Guest: Well, the way that example was set up, it was as if this is really a catastrophic asteroid and something is going to have to be done, and it would make people nervous--it would make me nervous--to just stall for 10 years, even, because we really want to dig into the science of this and run some experiments and get in place asteroid-deflecting technology and so forth. And the fact that that would alter or destroy civilization or much of life on earth makes it, would dominate our image or it would dominate mine. And I think that climate change has this probabilistic uncertain aspect to it. The probability of really bad outcomes is nerve-rackingly high. And there is a lot of inertia in this. And people don't--that's another thing that makes this so hard to contemplate--there's very wide misconception on flows versus stocks. It's as simple as that. To get the stable--the goal is to stabilize the stock of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere. It's not to stabilize the flow. So if we cap the flow at this year's level, that would not stabilize carbon dioxide stocks, which would continue to rise. Russ: The total amount that's already in the atmosphere. Guest: Yeah. Russ: Use your bathtub analogy, because I like that. Guest: Yeah. Well, it's like a bathtub, where, there was water going in, let's say, and there was water coming out of the drain, and the bathtub height of water was something like a foot--12 inches. And so the incoming water was just matched by the outgoing water, and it remained at this 12-inch level. That's sort of what the planet was like before, with respect to carbon dioxide. Now, we've pushed up the spigot so that what's happening now, that 12 inches is going up. The stock of it is going up. And it's going up as we're turning up the spigot on carbon dioxide. But suppose you said, now, wait a minute, we've been turning up this spigot for 30, 40 years now. Let's stop turning up the spigot. Let's just leave it at where it is now. Then that would continue to accumulate, the height of water in the bathtub. So, let's say it was 12 inches; we turned up the spigot incrementally with time, and now the water is at 24 inches. And we say, 'Let's leave the spigot now at where it is now,' we've already brought the water from 12 inches to 24 inches. If you held it at where the spigot, at 24 inches is pouring water in, it would cause the height of the water to continue to go up, maybe to 36 inches and overflow the tub. So, it's not nearly enough to stabilize the flows of emissions. To stabilize emissions, you've got to lower the spigot. You've got to lower the emissions. Russ: To stabilize the stock. To stabilize the water level, or the stock of CO2 in the atmosphere. Guest: Yes. And that's the part--that's another part that's just so worrisome, that people are thinking in terms of 'Well, let's limit emissions.' Sometimes they are lowered, but let's limit emissions--so the Chinese have pledged that as of 2030 they will, at least as of 2030, they will start lowering their emissions. Well, they'll stabilize or lower their emissions. Well, if they stabilize the emissions levels in 2030, that's still going to cause a massive rise in the stock of CO2, and eventually result in the perception of a catastrophe. Russ: So, that's alarming. And I just want to mention that--I happened to see today on Twitter, Nassim Taleb put up a letter he had co-authored that argues that the increasing amount of uncertainty about the uncertainty just makes the case even stronger that we ought to do something. I'll try to find a link to that if we can. |
44:14 | On the positive side--I want to turn now to geo-engineering, which is a last third of the book or so. But before I do, I just want to say on the positive side, we have seen some technology improvement--quite dramatic, actually--in, say, the amount of energy that's used per dollar of GDP; as technology has gotten more efficient, energy use has gotten more efficient. We have turned increasingly to natural gas because of recent discoveries, that is lower carbon content than, say, oil, crude oil. So, there is some--it's true the rate is still increasing of the stock in the atmosphere. But it is increasing at perhaps a slightly decreasing rate, even as the people in the world get richer and use more energy. Which is something I certainly hope for. So these kind of technology improvements would have to be large enough to offset those increases in material well-being on those people's parts, correct? Guest: Yes. If you look at carbon dioxide emissions per unit of GDP, they decrease somewhat. Something less than or about 1% a year. But if the world is growing at 2% a year, or China is growing at 7% a year, that overwhelms the lower carbon dioxide emissions per growth of GDP because some of these countries are projected to grow so fast. And yes, the costs have been lowered significantly on solar technology and on wind technology. The total energy coming from them, worldwide, is still pretty minuscule. Russ: Trivial. Guest: Yeah. Absolutely. And no one is sure what would happen if you had a massive ramp-up, if you scaled this up. If you try to think about a world where wind and solar are each contributing 25% or something like that, that is a very different world, with windmills all over the place and deserts covered with solar panels. And neither of those two yet--neither the solar nor the wind--has conquered this devil's problem of, how do you store the stuff? Because they are intermittent sources. They can't be base loaded. You can't depend upon them. The only technology out there that is carbon free that is tested would be base-loaded nuclear. Russ: Oooh, oooh, don't say that word. Guest: That's right. Russ: No, that's the only really attractive, viable solution, at least right now. But it's got a lot of bad pub. And perhaps deservedly so. I don't despair, but-- Guest: I think it's undeserved. People just have a fear button on that side. The French have significantly lower emissions of carbon dioxide per French citizen than the Germans have emitted carbon dioxide per German citizen, and Germany has really pulled out a lot of the stops. There's a lot of wind power there. There's a lot of solar. But they still are nowhere near the French level, which is based primarily on nuclear power. Yeah, it's gotten very bad press, I think. There are problems with it, but everything has to be viewed in the light of what the alternatives are. Russ: Everything has problems. Camels in Canada, which is an image that you evoke, if we approach some of the prehistorical levels of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere, camels in Canada, that's a horrifying thought. Yes, a nuclear meltdown that gives people a higher chance of cancer at a younger age is a terrible tragedy. But it probably beats not being able to grow food in most of the world, or many other things we could imagine. It's an interesting challenge that the activists who are most worried about climate change are often most hostile to nuclear. For whatever reason. It would be interesting to collect all of the politically viable, imaginable things we could think of, short of cap and trade, short of a $40 carbon tax: if we let nuclear be easier to get to, if we increased urbanization, if we made it easier to get to natural gas, if we gave a prize for solar and wind. Those are all politically viable. Maybe not the nuclear right now. But the other ones, we could imagine. It would be interesting--and I don't know if anyone has tried to calculate how much we could dent the problem with those kind of, with a cumulative bunch of solutions like that. Policies like that. Guest: Yeah. Calculations have been made. Nuclear would come out a major player if you had a high enough price on carbon. The typical environmentalist views climate change problem as urgent, as a big problem. They also are opposed, typically, to nuclear power and to genetically modified organisms (GMOs), and I think they've got one of those three right--that's that climate change really is dangerous and scary. But I don't agree with the positions on the other two. Mark Lynas, who is a famous environmentalist and has written on climate change and lots of other environmental issues, agrees on this that nuclear power has a real place and it's important. And genetically modified food looks like it could be a real boon. So, most of the scientists that work with climate change think it's worrisome. Scientists that work directly with nuclear power think that's manageable; and the scientists who work with genetically modified organisms think there's a tremendous amount of promise for alleviating hunger and doing other good things around the world. So this environmental movement has slid[?] from the scientific consensus, as it were, on these two--nuclear and genetically modified organisms. Russ: Well, I do worry about their objectivity. You would expect engineers in the nuclear field to be optimistic about its safety, perhaps. Maybe you'd expect scientists working on GMOs to be less worried about it than others. But there is evidence that those things are relatively safer, at least not as likely to be catastrophically destructive as 6-plus degrees Celsius increase. |
51:31 | Russ: Let's move to geo-engineering. I found that quite interesting. We've talked about it very briefly in the past on the program: we've touched on it. And you go into some detail. Why don't you start with talking about Mount Pinatubo and what that did as a way to open people up to the idea that there could be some improvements of geoengineering; in particular, the leveraging effect that you talk about is very dramatic and provocative. Guest: Yes, well, Mount Pinatubo was an explosive volcanic eruption that threw lots of stuff into the sky, and lots of it high up into the stratosphere. And it sent out a massive amount--not a massive amount, but a large amount of sulfur dioxide into the stratosphere. That acted, that combined with other molecules there, acted as a reflector of the sun, and it cut sunlight by 1 or 2%, which was enough to send temperatures down by a half a degree centigrade for the next year or two. We've known about this effect of calderas, of explosive volcanoes, for a long time, and their effects have been observed over centuries--that after, in their aftermath, temperatures go down significantly. And the idea is okay--this is done by nature, whether we like it or not. Why don't human beings imitate nature? Would that be a good policy to actually seed the stratosphere with sulfur dioxide? One of the things that is amazing about this is how incredibly cheap it is to lower temperatures by geoengineering--solar radiation management forms of geoengineering. To lower earth's average surface temperature by 1 or 2 degrees centigrade would cost less than $10 billion a year. You need a fleet of planes or rockets or something like that to keep pushing this stuff into the stratosphere, but there's not that much that's needed. And it's incredibly cheap. So, you compare what it costs to lower temperatures by a degree from geoengineering, with how much it would cost to lower temperatures by a degree via new technologies or via solar and wind--it's overwhelmingly cheaper to fool with the sulfur dioxide. And that's something we didn't need, we don't need--the economics of climate change is already the economic problem from hell because of all these complexities, because it's an international public good, because of timing, because of lots of things-- Russ: It's a wicked problem. Guest: And now you've suddenly made it more wicket. Because you've really got two externalities of public goods out there. The one, the traditional one, is that people free ride because it's so expensive to change from a carbon burning technology and everyone wants to free ride. Here you've the opposite kind of public goods or international problem, where many, many nations, and even individuals could afford this $10 billion a year; and somehow you need governance of both of these things. So, in a sense, it's twice as difficult an international public goods problem as we thought it was before geoengineering emerged as a kind of a conceptional at least alternative. Russ: It seems like a very attractive insurance policy. On the surface. I guess the issue, which you touched on in the book is, well, a lot of people would say, 'That's playing God.' We're already playing God; we're putting the carbon into the atmosphere, so that part's not so alarming. It's really the unintended consequences. So, what do we know, if anything--well, you just sort of said, 'Well, you put a bunch of planes up there; you put up the sulfur into the atmosphere.' What are the worries? Guest: Oh. There are many worries. I think this has a place as a kind of Plan B, in case--we need to do research to know what this is about just in case some catastrophic outcomes emerge. You've got a series of issues where it would affect the weather patterns. It would affect the weather patterns; it's probably going to make the ozone hole more of a problem. Ocean acidification would proceed apace because you are not changing the carbon dioxide in the atmosphere. You are changing the amount of sunlight that's hitting the earth, basically. There's an argument that you might become dependent upon this. Suppose that you are thinking of temporary particles like sulfur dioxide which will come out of the stratosphere within a year or so--supposed you got hooked on that, and then you discovered that it's got some very bad side effects, maybe some Black Swan side effects that are really bad, terrible. Russ: Feedback loops that you weren't aware of. Guest: Right, right, right. Now if you go off of that solar radiation management geoengineering, there is an abrupt increase in temperatures. So, this thing is a blessing and a curse. It will immediately cause the temperatures to go down, but if you want to get away from it, it will immediately cause the temperatures to go up throughout the planet, in too rapid a way. If this hubris argument, that carries a lot of weight, that 'Look, we geoengineer the planet already--that's what's causing the problem of climate change and the problems of future climate change. Now we're going to geoengineer it the opposite way,' there's too much human tampering with the system. There's a moral hazard type of an argument that's out there that's--I don't myself much subscribe to this--but if people knew that this cheap method was available for cutting down carbon dioxide, they would go towards that as a solution rather than cutting carbon dioxide emissions. Russ: All right, so we can't talk about it. It's too dangerous. Guest: Yeah, there's a bunch of possibly bad issues. It's a gamble. What I think is, we need more research in this area; that truly can be said. So we shouldn't be--it's probably politically correct not to do more research in this area, but we need more research even if we're not using this thing. Even if we come down deciding it should not be used, we need research on how this is going to be done, what the effects would be. And so forth. And I think it needs to be out there as a Plan B, just in case. Russ: Your remark about hubris, that this is how we got in the problem--our over-confidence in our ability to manage the planet, this is how we got into the problem to start with; we could fix it by doing the same thing: I just have to say, having seen Avengers: Age of Ultron this week, that it's the Tony Stark effect. Which--it's kind of a spoiler, perhaps. I don't want to say it, how it turns out in the movie. But there is this--I've kind of got my tongue in cheek there because it's hard to imagine that I could spoil the ending for anybody, whether it's a happy or unhappy one. |
1:00:14 | Russ: I want to close with a sociological observation and let you respond to it. I found your book pushed me somewhat toward being somewhat more concerned about climate change than I was before. I'm generally in the agnostic/skeptic camp. Mainly because I do see these parallels with macroeconomics; I'm not really convinced the macro is much of a science, and I see a similar complexity problem unfurling in climate change. And a similar problem with the advocates being way too confident, given what I see as the uncertainty about their estimation techniques and science. Your book is a breath of fresh air in that sense, in that you don't overclaim. You are extremely modest; and yet despite that modesty you still want some dramatic solutions. Which I'm slightly more interested in being in favor of after reading your book. Do you think this clamor on the part of scientists and activists, the overconfidence that they project relative to the imprecision of their numbers, is part of the problem? Do you think that the problem has been marketed badly, to put it in bald language? Because I do. I referred earlier to Al Gore being a spokesperson; I think that was a terrible marketing blunder. I mean, no one chose it; it just happened because of his prominence and Nobel Prize and all that--and his movie. But do you think that, in terms of speaking to your fellow warriors--and I put you in the worrying camp--do you think tone and style are important in getting people to change their minds or important in getting people to change their minds or to be alarmed about something that might be 100 years away? Guest: I think it probably does play a role. And I've thought about what is the best way to present this. I don't know any other way except that it's got to emphasize that we'll probably be all right if we can keep levels moderate. But it does have this disaster side to it that really should make people nervous. If some climate scientists or the majority come across as overly confident, I know they can't be confident--they can be confident about the big picture but they can't be confident about very many specifics at all. And it's [?] this asymmetric distribution where, okay, by their talking maybe they're conveying that they are more sure than they actually are. But if they are wrong in one direction, the consequences are much greater than if they are wrong in the other direction. And that's still a huge part of the problem. It's a wicked problem, because of this timing. You've got something occurring that's very long by the measures of the political cycles or people's lifetimes, even. But it's a remarkably short experiment by geophysical. And that's what causes a lot of the uncertainty. We haven't seen this in millions of years. So, it's right there in between. It's geologically instantaneous, which makes us very unsure about the probabilities and everything else about it; and it's much longer than even a human lifetime, which makes people want to put it away and say, 'Let's worry about this when it starts occurring.' Russ: Well, you and I will probably not be alive in 2100. I don't expect to be. But there's a pretty good chance that my children, who were born in the 1990s, they'll be alive in 2100. They may not make it, for a bunch of reasons, obviously, but there's a chance that they will. If they have children, they will, those children are very likely to be alive in 2100. So, my grandchildren, it's their lives that are at risk. So it's not that long a span. I guess it's hard to think about your unborn grandchildren and worrying about them, but certainly the next generation, either my children or their children's children, will have a worry about this, if it is indeed worrisome, that will be very different from ours. Because they will live longer; it will fall much more--it's more likely to fall in their lifespan. Guest: I agree with you. Look, 2100 is very hard to think of, it's so far away. But what makes the part of, again making this problem so devilish, is that a lot--there's going to be bad consequences. Really bad consequences. They are going to come in after 2100. Actions now and in the near or middle future are going to impact the planet not just in 2100: certain things will be showing up by then, I believe. But beyond that, you are condemning, sort of future centuries to some very bad things. That's how--people can't even think in terms of 2100. How are they supposed to think in terms of 2200? Which is when a lot of disastrous things really would start to materialize. Russ: A couple of weeks ago we had Eric Topol on talking about technological change in medicine. So, we'll be living to 150, 200 years, no doubt. Although he did not predict that. I don't want to put words in his mouth. But there are some interesting things coming in medicine that may extend lifespans. We'll see. Do you want to close with something optimistic? That was a pretty cheerless close. Do you have anything optimistic to say? Guest: Uh, well. Anything optimistic--I keep chipping along, hoping for the realization that we need to put a price on carbon dioxide and greenhouse gases. And maybe we can push that argument forward to where people find it acceptable. There was an interesting, very interesting experiment in British Columbia where they put a tax on carbon. But they rebated it by having a per capita check to everyone go out, and they very wisely first had the check go out and then put in the tax on carbon. And that worked. It worked--at first it was very controversial. Business didn't like it. But they got it through. And now, it's so ingrained that if you are going to take off that tax, it's politically difficult because then you've got to name where you are going to get the taxes from. So, my hope--the optimistic thing--is that more and more of the world sees this British Columbia style system and is enticed to adapt it. |
READER COMMENTS
Scott Packard
Jun 1 2015 at 9:48am
In the Lundberg survery:
https://docs.google.com/file/d/0B10tltNyRvx6ZkhQWGxURWhNd1k/view
(This is a Calif. cap-and-trade implementation for fuels/CO2/Global Warming, and an observation of where monies are being redirected)
The collection of funds from AB32 is already huge. So huge that new avenues for assignment of the funds are cropping up like weeds. Last year’s state budget earmarked 35% or $130-million of “global warming” funds for affordable housing.
Governor Brown’s budget proposal would add $400-million for housing projects. Nearly
all of the nearly $200-million spent on the state’s “bullet train” project has come from the cap-&-trade and FUC fees.
Dan
Jun 1 2015 at 12:37pm
The climate has and always will change. This has been going on for thousands of years without man’ involvement. Jefferson and Noah Webster warned of increasing temperatures in the late 1700’s. How’d that turn out?
Fact:The temperature stopped increasing 18 years ago despite the increase in green house gas.
As the previous post implies- follow the money trail. A whole industry has started due to the illusion of climate change, mostly funded with taxpayer dollars. The University of Minnesota recently received a $4 million grant to study the effects of climate change on the prairie. How objective will they be??
Floccina
Jun 1 2015 at 1:16pm
1. It might be cheaper to remove co2 from the atmosphere. (Deep ocean iron fertilization/biochar are 2 methods.)
2. He ignores the possibility that global warming could be saving us from an ice age.
3. 2 million people live in Manaus Brazil, 146 live on Ellesmere Island? Warmer appears to better for humans especially since the invention of air conditioners.
Never the less I would support a co2 tax (I would like to see it paired with a payout for removing co2 from the air) but I do not support cap and trade which seems like it would be easier for politicians to use to scam the voters and taxpayers.
I also think that it quite safe to wait.
Speed
Jun 1 2015 at 1:32pm
Weitzman said, ” … what we estimated is that if the greenhouse gas concentrations double, the chance of being greater than 4.5 degrees centigrade is around 10%. If greenhouse gas concentrations double, the probability of being greater than 6 degrees centigrade response is around 3%. So this is the bad tail of climate sensitivity, which is symbolic of the bad tail of what the damages could be. And these numbers just seem alarming, with the doubling of CO2, which is almost inevitable, there is a 3% chance of having temperatures greater than, a temperature response greater than 6 degrees.”
Catastrophic Global Warming alarmists postulate that temperature rise will reach the “potentially horrendous” level of +6°C by from the inclusion of major positive feedbacks from additional water vapor in the atmosphere. The +6°C temperature level would still only bring global temperatures only to about the level of the previous Eemian maximum.
The Eemian interglacial ~120,000 years ago, was a warm and more plentiful period in the worlds recent history: hippopotami thrived in the Rhine delta. As ice sheets substantially receded in the Eemian, resulting sea levels were about 3 meters higher than found at present. But that ice sheet disintegration process would have taken millennia to be fulfilled.
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2015/06/01/ice-core-data-shows-the-much-feared-2c-climate-tipping-point-has-already-occurred/
The tail may be fat but there is no reason to believe that it will be all bad. Or even mostly bad.
Joe
Jun 1 2015 at 1:59pm
It strikes me that the concerns/arguments of the proponents that are suggesting for societies to take climate science serious (and be progressive on action) are analogous to concerns/arguments for proponents of too much national debt. Both argue that there is this possible, although small, catastrophic risk if we do nothing. The cynic in me wonders (in a two party system) why I can’t vote for both issues to be proactive or both issues to be of little concern. Once again it appears that the political parties have ‘divided the spoils’ and I can’t be consistent when I go to the poles. (other examples are I can’t vote pro-life and against the death penalty; I can’t vote pro social welfare and against government waste etc. – there are many if you think it through.)
S M V
Jun 1 2015 at 2:51pm
I disagree with Mr. Weitzman on many things, but I think he is correct when he states that some level of insurance would be prudent, given how easy and low cost it could be to implement.
Simply impose a $50/ton carbon tax while reducing FICA by 10-12%. The two would offset each other at about $100 billion. As carbon usage in the US dropped taxes flowing to Washington would drop.
Once the debate is firmly about what other taxes would be reduced to offset the new carbon tax then the two parties can compete to give the tax reductions to their special interests and to increase the size of the reduction.
SMV
Speed
Jun 1 2015 at 4:54pm
From Reuters …
U.N. climate deal in Paris may be graveyard for 2C goal
The U.N.’s Paris climate conference, designed to reach a plan for curbing global warming, may instead become the graveyard for its defining goal: to stop temperatures rising more than 2 degrees Celsius above pre-industrial levels.
http://www.reuters.com/article/2015/06/01/us-climatechange-paris-insight-idUSKBN0OH1G820150601
Ralph
Jun 1 2015 at 6:52pm
The ice core data demonstrates that CO2 change follows temperature change. Every time you see AlGore stand in front of that graph of temperature and CO2, he’s committing fraud. Yes there is a relationship, but it is the opposite – temperatures drive CO2 change. The graph time-line is so long that the thickness of the graph lines disguises the several hundred years lag time from temperature increase to subsequent CO2 increase. It’s physics – increased temperatures increase the partial pressure of CO2 above a fluid mixture (oceans in this case).
Weitzman uses a lot of numbers and makes it sound like science, but there’s still no evidence for his assumptions. You can invent any proposal and make estimates and derive percentages, but that doesn’t make it any more real. How many angels can dance on the head of a pin? Man-made Global Warming is a false religion, and this presentation is the equivalent of Pascal’s Wager.
Man-made global warming hypothesis assumes that increased greenhouse gases will increase atmospheric temperatures and subsequently increase surface temperature – it is an atmospheric phenomenon. Given the lack of objective atmospheric evidence, any study that cites increasing surface temperatures is actually disproving the Man-made global warming hypothesis – there must be some other cause of the increased surface temperatures (including fudging the data).
He’s correct that the money from a carbon tax doesn’t just go away: it transfers from individuals to an ambiguous “us” or “we” that hides the political favorites of the redistributionists in government – socialize costs and concentrate benefits.
Recognize that “stabilizing” emissions means capping industrial outputs.
Dan Hanson
Jun 1 2015 at 7:54pm
Some thoughts while listening to this podcast:
1. It seems the social cost of carbon is essentially a justification for a Pigouvian tax, meant to offset damage from an externality. But if demand for fossil fuel is inelastic, why would that necessarily drive down consumption of carbon-based energy to the point where global warming can be kept manageable? A GDP neutral tax that doesn’t slow CO2 emissions isn’t much good for anything other than flowing more capital through the hands of politicians.
2. If the U.S. unilaterally raises the cost of its own energy, would that not simply increase the comparative advantage for those countries that enjoy cheap fossil fuels? Why would Russia and China go along with this deal after the U.S. unilaterally puts itself at a disadvantage against them, so long as they don’t follow suit?
3. If the tax isn’t global, isn’t it likely that the ultimate result will simply be a wealth transfer to countries like China and Russia? Wouldn’t heavy industry simply move there over time, thus perhaps making the problem even worse if their energy efficiency is lower and therefore the carbon footprint of those goods increases?
4. If this is just management of fat-tailed risk, and not a progressive political program in disguise, why aren’t the same people more worried about other systemic risks?
For example, it’s been estimated that there’s about a 12% per decade chance that a solar coronal mass ejection event will hit the earth and take out our satellites and our power grid and a lot of our electronics and computers. The effect of that on mankind would be devastating, yet I don’t hear anyone talking about it.
My suspicion is that it’s not a huge issue because it’s not easy to turn it into an excuse to transfer political and economic power to favoured groups.
5. This was touched on in the interview, but in my opinion if someone believes that global warming will devastate mankind and the planet, but refuses to even consider ramping up nuclear power, there is another agenda in play.
6. You will never get a global agreement on a strategy for the simple reason that climate change affects different countries in different ways. We talk about the ‘social cost of carbon’ as a global number, but it really isn’t – it will be different for every country.
Canada and Russia might be net beneficiaries – we have a lot of permafrost that might open up to agriculture, and the opening of the Northwest Passage would be a boon to both countries. On the other hand, warmer countries with significant populated coastline would be much harder hit.
Good interview, as usual!
steve hardy
Jun 1 2015 at 9:35pm
According to Pat Michaels at the Cato Institute:
“Assuming the IPCC’s value for climate sensitivity (i.e. disregarding the recent scientific literature) and completely stopping all carbon dioxide emissions in the U.S. between now and the year 2050 and keeping them at zero, will only reduce the amount of global warming by just over a tenth of a degree (out of a total projected rise of 2.619°C between 2010 and 2100).”
For more on this and a Handy Dandy Carbon Tax Temperature Savings Calculator see http://www.cato.org/blog/current-wisdom-we-calculate-you-decide-handy-dandy-carbon-tax-temperature-savings-calculator
Stéphane Couvreur
Jun 2 2015 at 12:35am
Thanks for this discussion. I just recently read Climate casino, by William Nordhaus. Rather than focus on extreme events, he looks at averages to determine the right course of action. One weakness of his approach is that average is not impressive : the impact of global warming on global GDP in the median scenario looks small, something like a 5% loss. When talking about GDP in year 2100, such a small difference is a joke.
So I was more receptive to the approach of Weitzman: let’s reduce the probability of a disastrous event, even though the meaning of “probability” in this context is very fuzzy (single, complex future event).
In terms of solution, both Nordhaus and Weitzman advocate a carbon tax which is generally presented in terms of $ per ton of carbon. I find this unite hard to grasp. Global current emissions being around 10Gt per year, a high carbon tax of $100 per ton would represent $1 trillion, roughly 1:75th (1,33%) of world GDP which struck me as a rather small incentive to move away from fossil fuels. How much would the price of carbon-emitting energy increase, in %? In the same spirit, how large are the current subsidies to carbon? We need these orders of magnitude.
At one point Russ asks whether there can be a sustained, economically efficient, global cooperative effort. Nordhaus cites the examples of sulfur dioxide and CFCs, which were handled using a combination of cap and trade and regulations. No tax? Yet he advocates, like Weitzman, a carbon tax as politically more feasible. One crucial issue is: who gets the proceeds? In the case of sulfur dioxide, the industry went along with the plan because it was granted property rights on its preexisting emissions. But Nordhaus clearly favors a tax in order to increase government spending… Who should get to proceeds? Can the proceeds really be used to reduce other distortionary taxes as Weitzman suggests? This sounds a bit naive.
Last point: about nuclear, at the time scale we are discussing, thorium should be part of the discussion. Yet, for the moment, several countries are massively subsidizing a nuclear fusion prototype (ITER), which sounds like a total waste of resources at this stage. Look at Kirk Sorensen and Jean-Christophe de Mestral to learn about molten salt thorium reactors, the so-called “green nuclear energy”.
Gene Banman
Jun 2 2015 at 11:12am
Russ,
I’m particularly interested in your series on Climate Change. I must say you have had a profound impact on my view of the issue. However, my position is still a little closer to Weitzman’s than yours.
I couple of comments. Regarding your skepticism that an international agreement of some form for the reduction of carbon being practical, I would point to the WTO, NAAFTA, the EU, etc. It is a patchwork, but over the last 60 years the world has done an amazing job of reducing trade barriers. It is far from perfect, but it could be a model for implementing an agreement on a carbon tax. Its an existence proof that international cooperation can be achieved if the goal is simple and is beneficial (even when many don’t see it that way).
Now I would like to chide you a bit about your response to the $40/lb carbon tax outlined by your guest. You responded by asking Weitzman if we would spend 50% or 30% of world GDP to prevent a asteroid collision. This implied, stated or not, that the $40/lb tax was something on that order. A $40/lb carbon tax is orders of magnitude less than that kind of level.
I’m quite excited about the potential for technological climate cooling technologies. However, I do worry that the technology to stop the acidification of the oceans will be the same as reducing carbon.
Keep up the good work, Russ. Thanks for all you do.
An avid listener,
Gene
Speed
Jun 2 2015 at 12:06pm
Martin Weitzman said, “For the last 35 years, the uncertainty around this climate sensitivity, this temperature response, has not much changed. Thirty five years ago in some of the first early engineering studies it was stated that it’s likely between 1.5 degree centigrade and 3.5 degree centigrade–oh, I’m sorry–it’s likely between 1.5 degrees centigrade and 4.5 degrees centigrade. That’s a pretty wide range, 1.5-4.5 degrees centigrade. And that’s in the latest IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) report from last year, it gives that same range. So that, what’s happened, seemingly, is that although there has been much, much more research into climate change, and many, many more models and observations, we must be–as we are resolving some of the uncertainty about something like climate sensitivity, new forms of uncertainty are emerging.”
In other words, the calculated value of climate sensitivity has been unchanged for many years and is therefore likely correct.
For recent updates on Climate Sensitivity see …
Implications of recent multimodel attribution studies for climate sensitivity
http://climateaudit.org/2015/06/02/implications-of-recent-multimodel-attribution-studies-for-climate-sensitivity/#more-21165
… and …
The implications for climate sensitivity of AR5 forcing and heat uptake estimates
http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s00382-014-2342-y
(Dr. Curry is a past econtalk guest)
Speed
Jun 2 2015 at 12:18pm
More on climate sensitivity
Judith Curry writes …
The vociferous objections to the iris hypothesis arises not so much from the hypothesis per se, but rather its implications for climate sensitivity. In 2001, around the time of the IPCC TAR, there was a great deal of animosity towards any scientist or paper that argued for a low value of climate sensitivity …
[quoting Lintzen] … what will happen to the exponentially growing climate change community if the sensitivity of climate to global forcing is small? Could the wish to avoid this question be the reason why our ‘official’ estimates of climate sensitivity have not improved since the Charney Report of 1979?
http://judithcurry.com/2015/05/26/observational-support-for-lindzens-iris-hypothesis/
Buzz
Jun 2 2015 at 4:12pm
There is a lot of uncertainty because climate is a very complex and chaotic system. The bottom-line however is:
1. Green-house effect is real
2. CO2 levels have been climbing since the start of the industrial revolution
If you agree with these then there’s no doubt that global warming is real and man made. It might not be linear, some heat might be stored in the oceans, and so on, but if you keep putting a constant amount of energy into a system and let less and less escape, then sooner or later the temperature of that system will rise.
Tom Graham
Jun 2 2015 at 4:43pm
Russ,
I thoroughly enjoy your EconTalk conversations. Thank you so much — particularly for introducing Adam Smith’s THEORY OF MORAL SENTIMENTS to me. Your book is wonderful!
I’m amazed at the persistence of the CAGW paradigm, which appears to grow more strident even as the “pause” continues and the shoddy “science” becomes more and more exposed. It appears to me quite likely that the entire global warming argument may become moot within the next 3-5 years with technological development in the realm of nuclear energy — but NOT with conventional high pressure liquid water reactors (which are inherently unsafe, EXTREMELY expensive, and flawed in other ways, but with an emerging Molten Salt Reactor technology. There are several startup ventures working to relaunch this technology since it was shut down for political reasons by Richard Nixon at Oak Ridge National Labs in the 1970s. It seems inevitable that this technology will emerge and drastically curtail CO2 production because the safe modular nuclear power will be so cheap!
I wonder if you might consider interviewing one of the leaders of Terrestrial Energy, Inc. http://terrestrialenergy.com/directors-and-officers/
for insights on this pending revolution?
Buzz
Jun 2 2015 at 4:44pm
Dan Hanson:
1. Why would demand for fossil fuels be inelastic ?
2. If it’s a revenue neutral carbon tax, then there will be other industries that benefit.
3. There will be some migration of CO2 heavy industries to countries who don’t do the carbon tax, but imo that would be minor. Apply the carbon tax to products imported from countries who are major polluters and you have it mostly solved.
Josiah
Jun 2 2015 at 5:35pm
There will be some migration of CO2 heavy industries to countries who don’t do the carbon tax, but imo that would be minor.
Particularly if you have border adjustments.
Robert Wiblin
Jun 2 2015 at 5:46pm
I think Weitzman did a great job of making the case in this podcast.
I find it frustrating listening to Russ cast doubt on the importance of climate change, because it seems so clearly ideologically motivated.
As Weitzman points out, not being able to model the climate very well is an argument *in favour* of not meddling with the climate, not against it. If you can’t predict what will happen, don’t take the risk!
Looking at a longer time series of temperatures, the ‘pause’ looks pretty irrelevant, if it’s there at all: http://climate.nasa.gov/vital-signs/global-temperature/
Morgan Dubiel
Jun 2 2015 at 10:08pm
Dear Robert Wiblin,
NASA, a government sponsored political operation, choose too short a timeline. The Earth is 4.54 billion years old or so. It’s been hotter.
The 134 years of NASA’s study are just noise in the whole scheme of things.
Perhaps it’s the melting of the Arctic ice that has you concerned?
But then take a look at the mirror image compensating for that in the Antarctic.
Let’s take a look at temps since the last ice age.
We can agree that climate change is real. It’s happening now and has happened throughout earth’s history. What we cannot agree on is that the miniscule addition of freeing previously trapped carbon by human beings is causing it. It might be part of it, but it most certainly isn’t the driver or anything significant. Otherwise, how did CO2 and temps rise previously in history? More importantly, demonstrate from earth’s history the negative effects of high CO2 concentrations and temperatures. There isn’t any.
Given how well government has done things to date, particularly big, important things, I’m not at all in favor of giving government more things to do or the money to do them.
Lenny55
Jun 3 2015 at 1:39am
I am just a poor old history major, but I do listen to EconTalk.
When I weigh the risk factors between a 10% chance of a climate disaster if we do nothing about CO2 emissions against the 100% chance of worldwide economic and societal disaster if draconian reductions of CO2 are implemented, I’ll take the 10% chance and do nothing.
Floccina
Jun 3 2015 at 9:43am
@Joe I think that government does so much these now, that we need to un-bundle things. We could vote for an executive of benevolence and executive environment, an executive if transportation, defense. Each would come with his own tax proposal. You would still need a president to declare war and run the FBI and the federal court system.
Of course I see no way to get there but it might help to think about what might be an improvement.
Ken Simpson
Jun 3 2015 at 1:56pm
Wait. “Expert” (sic) climate “scientists” (sic) have not been able to model climate change within a standard deviation. Yet, we are supposed to allow bureaucrats to calculate the monetary cost of all future climate change, over decades and centuries, discounted to present dollars? Ridiculous.
Last group of climate alarmists I saw were drinking imported water. Go figure.
Hesam
Jun 3 2015 at 3:56pm
During the conversation it was repeated that the atmospheric concentration of Carbon Dioxide is 440 ppm at the moment. However only very recently it was in the news that we just passed the 400 ppm milestone and Wikipedia has the same number:
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Carbon_dioxide_in_Earth%27s_atmosphere
Increasing at 2 ppm per year that difference of 40 ppm is pretty huge.
Steffen Hentrich
Jun 3 2015 at 5:23pm
Very interesting podcast but slightly unbalanced. Weitzmans “Dismal Theorem” has been criticized in recent years. For instance Ross McKitrick (Professor of Economics at the University of Guelph) summarized the critic recently and shows in addition that Weitzmans Theorem should properly be seen as an extreme, and implausible, special case (see “Cheering up the Dismal Theorem”). He shows that if using an exact measure of the percentage change in consumption instead of Weitzman’s approximation “the price of insurance [against climate change] becomes unbounded in a special case in which a market for insurance is impossible anyway, namely if we know that future consumption will be zero and there is no transferring wealth between periods, and even then only for some values of risk aversion parameter.” Much less dismal outcomes are the norm. Maybe Russ Roberts should also interview Prof. McKitrick to get a some more balanced debate.
Broadfoot
Jun 4 2015 at 6:07pm
NOT EVEN CLOSE, about an order of magnitude too low.
Fact: Burning a gallon of gasoline results in 19.64 pounds of CO2 emissions. Source: http://www.eia.gov/tools/faqs/faq.cfm?id=307&t=11
19.64 lb/gal * 1 tonne / 2205 lb * $40/tonne = $0.356/gal of gasoline.
Fact: The average US household buys about 1000 gallons of gasoline per year. Source: http://ns.umich.edu/new/releases/22761-gasoline-use-at-lowest-rate-in-three-decades
So, a carbon tax will run about $360/year for the average US household. It’s trivial to a tenured Harvard professor, but a painful burden to low-income households. And here’s the rub: if low-income households get carbon tax relief because of their low income, then the tax will be without effect. It’s well understood that automotive fuel is inelastic. Inferring from what Prof. Weitzman said, the tax is trivial to upper-middle and upper income people, so they won’t change their demand (4 cents, 40 cents, what difference does that make?) If lower-income people get tax relief, they won’t change their demand. So the carbon tax just becomes another burden on middle class people who have to drive to work.
Also, we should never, ever forget the income tax started off as a 3% tax on the “one-percent”. There is simply no telling where a carbon tax will end up.
But I’m sure Prof. Weitzman’s intentions are pure, so it’s all good.
Ken Simpson
Jun 4 2015 at 7:39pm
“Just because you’re paranoid doesn’t mean they aren’t after you.”
http://news.sciencemag.org/chemistry/2015/06/lost-and-found-earths-missing-heat
Now, these “scientists” (sic) are taking the best data we have, and “adjusting” them to fit their hypotheses.
And they wonder why some of us are so skeptical, and don’t believe the “science is settled“.
Richard Genz
Jun 5 2015 at 12:58pm
Good interview–as usual. Thanks.
Prof. Weitzman’s estimate of carbon tax impact on gasoline prices is far lower — by orders of magnitude — than estimates published in this week’s column by Eduardo Porter in the New York Times. Link:
http://www.nytimes.com/2015/06/03/business/energy-environment/climate-deal-badly-needs-a-big-stick.html?_r=0
Also, Russ Roberts, I understand you’re pretty skeptical about the reality and impact of climate change. Maybe that will change. I just hope you’re paying more attention to Nassim Taleb than to the Koch brothers (major patrons of your employer, George Mason University.)
Richie
Jun 5 2015 at 4:11pm
The guest mentioned a $40/ton carbon tax would work out to 4 cents/gallon of gas.
Would the purpose of the carbon tax be to curtail use, or to fund cleanup? I don’t think 4 cents per gallon would do anything to curtail usage. I would think it would take at least $1 to have any effect.
Richie
Jun 5 2015 at 4:12pm
@Broadfoot,
Unless I’m misunderstanding your comment, I think your math is off.
1,000 gallons per year x $0.356/gallon = $36/year NOT $360/year.
Broadfoot
Jun 6 2015 at 11:03am
@Richie,
Back when I went to school:
1000*0.356=356.
However, I must admit that I am geezer.
If it really does equal 36, my ignorance of this sort of new math may explain why I so often think Krugman’s arguments are nonsense.
Don Rudolph
Jun 6 2015 at 11:29am
I have never been clear on the overall effect of a couple degrees difference in temperature rise. Would Oregon have a northern California like climate and Washington state an Oregon like climate. If so would flora and fauna, and agricultural crops slowly drift north. That scenario seems not too catastrophic.
On the other hand dramatic and unpredictable changes could be catastrophic, like the midwest transforming into a sahara like dessert. These two scenarios teeter totter in my mind and I am alternately alarmed and relaxed at the thought of climate change.
Harvey Cody
Jun 6 2015 at 11:40am
Russ Roberts’s questions and comments in this podcast were outstanding! They elicited Mr. Weitzman’s views, and, more important, they probed in a respectful way many of the critical issues with respect to both climate science and proposed remedies which have been proposed because of that science.
Mr. Weitzman, on the other hand, while apparently knowledgeable about climate research, relatively reasonable in his assertions and did a fair job of representing one side of the climate debate, appeared not to comprehend many of the questions Russ posed, i.e., he was not able to grapple with many of the tough issues related to his topic. In general, no matter what Russ asked, Mr. Weitzman would respond by either presenting more supposedly scientific facts or saying things about how scary the boogey man is.
There were three glaring examples:
Russ’s third question was, “What’s the catastrophic outcome that you think we should worry about? And what would the consequences be?” Mr. Weitzman’s response had to do with the history of CO2 concentrations and the science with respect thereto, and concluded the Earth has not experienced CO2 levels which are expected to be reached before long (in geologic time) in the last 50 million years, i.e., his response included no attempt to describe the character or magnitude of the evils the boogey man will bestow on the world if he is, in fact, real.
Yet elsewhere, Mr. Weitzman wants the people to buy an insurance policy against this apparently indescribable and unquantifiable hazard. To determine whether insurance is a worthwhile expenditure, one must compare the cost of the insurance to the potential cost of incurring the risk (e.g., paying $300 for a three year extended warranty on $100 dollar item doesn’t make sense). Mr. Weitzman’s answer gives us nothing to go by to make this determination. It is one thing to say, as Mr. Weitzman does, that there is a 10% chance of something really, really bad happening. It is quite another to make the case that the price of insurance against that bad possibility is a good move. Mr. Weitzman gives us nothing on this critical issue.
At about 14:00 Russ notes there has been a 15 or 16 years pause in warming despite rising CO2 concentrations and then asks: “Does that give you any uncertainty about this relationship between greenhouse gases in the atmosphere and temperature and the likelihood that 700 parts per million is going to be 6-plus degrees centigrade hotter than it is now?” Mr. Weitzman acknowledges, “Well, I think it emphasizes how unsure we are,” but merely says that science is unable to predict climate on a year by year basis, and restates his claim with respect to the long term. This response has nothing to do with Russ’s question. Rather than grapple with the implications of the pause on the credibility of the science, he merely restates that the science shows that warming will increase over time.
About half way between 17:27 and 27:33 Russ asks a superb question: “What is the likely cost of [$40/ton of CO2 emissions] level of taxation on economic growth, or on people living in very poor places that desperately need energy to catch up?” While Mr. Weitzman made interesting points as to how, at least theoretically, governments could make the carbon tax revenue neutral by lowering other taxes or refunding the carbon tax, or could even boost economic activity, he did not, (and I suspect could not credibly) claim that either such a tax would be so implemented or that enough accurate information could be gathered so as to keep the tax from hurting the world’s poor.
Todd Kreider
Jun 6 2015 at 12:31pm
1) Russ: “Yes, a nuclear meltdown that gives people a higher chance of cancer at a younger age is a terrible tragedy. ”
No, meltdowns like what happened at Fukushima do not increase the risk of cancer in any meaningful sense.
The only people at risk were some works who got enough radiation to put them at a 1% increase of getting cancer. The last I read, twenty workers were in this 1% elevated risk category. They wouldn’t get cancer until around 2030 or 2040 when it could easily be cured.
2) Guest:” The French have significantly lower emissions of carbon dioxide per French citizen than the Germans have emitted carbon dioxide per German citizen, and Germany has really pulled out a lot of the stops.”
This is misleading. The overall EU tonnes of CO2 per person is 8.1. France is at the low end at 6.1 while Germany is slightly above average at 9.6.
Dan
Jun 6 2015 at 1:09pm
Good discussion: few opinions and many facts.
“Save the World/Globe/Planet” attitude is misplaced – we are nothing but temporary specks on this planet that has sustained life for a very long time – we can neither “save” nor “destroy” it.
Earth ecosystem is built with negative feedback loops and fail-safe mechanisms. That’s not to say that all individuals and species will survive a catastrophe, but species and individuals die out naturally anyway from time to time.
Broadfoot
Jun 6 2015 at 1:39pm
Left unsaid in this discussion is the actual target for reductions in US GHG emissions that is being advanced by our political elite.
Fact #1: Pres. Obama’s Copenhagen plan proposes a long-term target of an 83% reduction from 2005 emissions.
Fact #2: 2005 US GHG emissions = 6526 million tonnes
So the 17% target for 2050 is 1109 million tonnes.
Fact #3: Pew Reseach projects US population to be 438 million in 2050. A projection is not a fact, but this seems reasonable.
So, the President’s target is 2.53 tonnes of GHG emissions per capita by 2050.
Fact #4: Oak Ridge National Labs CO2 Information Analysis Center estimates that US annual CO2 emissions were 372.6 million tonnes in 1915, a century ago.
Fact #5: US Census Bureau reports that US population was between 100.5 million in 1915.
So, US GHG emissions were 3.71 tonnes of GHG per capita.
So, Obama’s plan is to reduce GHG emissions to just 68% of those of a century ago.
The absurdity of this plan should be clear. In 1915, just 2.5 million cars were registered in the US. Less than one-half of American houses had electricity; those which did typically had it for illumination only. Average life expectancy was 53 years.
It’s going to take much more than a tax of $40/tonne of CO2 to force Americans to live like this. The plan simply cannot be achieved without depopulation or near-universal impoverishment.
Fact 1: DOE, http://apps1.eere.energy.gov/news/news_detail.cfm/news_id=15650
Fact 2: EPA, http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/Downloads/ghgemissions/US-GHG-Inventory-2014-Chapter-Executive-Summary.pdf
Fact 3: Pew Research Center, http://www.pewsocialtrends.org/2008/02/11/us-population-projections-2005-2050/
Fact 4: DOE, ORNL, http://cdiac.ornl.gov/ftp/trends/co2_emis/usa.dat
Fact 5: US Census Bureau, https://www.census.gov/population/estimates/nation/popclockest.txt
Harvey Cody
Jun 6 2015 at 2:37pm
@Richard Genz
“…Russ Roberts, I understand you’re pretty skeptical about the reality and impact of climate change.”
I hope you do not believe that all so called “climate skeptics” base their skepticism merely on the two factors you cited. Moreover, no one who believes humans are causing all of the increase in CO2 air concentrations and that the net impact of climate change will be negative [surely anyone who thinks seriously about climate change would acknowledge that some good will result] and large should, without serious examination [something omitted by Mr. Weitzman’s comments], believe that the unintended negative consequences of measures to reduce emissions will not be greater than the negative consequences of climate change. Couple this with the fact that the negative consequences of doing something are certain and the negative consequences of climate change are not and caution, if not skepticism, is fully warranted by all.
As a matter of scientific inquiry, climate science is fascinating and could be of great practical use for planning purposes, if nothing else. On the other hand, there is a huge difference between climate science and doing something about what climate science
Critical factors to a reasoned decision about climate change include:
Given that to be effective CO2 emissions reductions must be effected with an enforceable worldwide mechanism to cause compliance. Moreover, those who cheat will gain a competitive advantage over those who comply – which will cause the cheaters to grow and the compliers shrink. If for these reasons or others one believes “doing something” about climate change is futile, then it doesn’t matter what the science says or how bad the consequences are.
If one believes that the net negative consequences of measures to reduce CO2 emissions are worse than the propounded net negative consequences of climate change, then it doesn’t matter what the science says or how bad the consequences are.
If one believes that even if the net consequences of measures to reduce CO2 emissions are equal to the net consequences of climate change, but that the poor of the world will be disproportionately harmed (and the non-poor will receive the offsetting benefit), then it doesn’t matter what the science says or how bad the consequences are.
If one believes that the probability of any number of other things (e.g., volcanos, plague, nuclear war, asteroids, solar storms, magnetic pole shift, Armageddon, etc.) are individually or collectively sufficiently high to either destroy life on Earth and/or overwhelm human efforts to reduce CO2 emissions, then it doesn’t matter what the science says or how bad the consequences are.
Temperature changes over time with our without changes in CO2 concentrations. Can scientists prove that temperatures will not continue to rise even if humans stopped all CO2 emissions? Of course not. Moreover, changes in CO2 concentrations occur naturally over time. With how much care and accuracy have scientists identified how much of the change in temperature if there is any will be concentrations is attributable to humans? Give how profitable it is to tout the evils of anthropogenic CO2 emissions and the perils to any scientist uttering otherwise, it is unlikely climate scientists would spend much time seeking the reverse side of their story.
The point is, it is possible that each of the above beliefs are wrong. On the other hand, science cannot prove that any of them are wrong. There is a strong case for skepticism.
BTW: I can assure you that the amount of money that has been bestowed on pro climate change scientists and pro climate change advocates pales in comparison to the Koch brother’s have contributed to Mercatus. Moreover, great efforts are made to hound anti climate change scientists out of the academy. It just doesn’t pay for scientists to study or espouse the positive consequences of climate change or the negative consequences of doing something about it.
Did you notice that George Soros pledged $1.1 billion to the Climate Policy Initiative?
Buzz
Jun 8 2015 at 12:19am
[Comment removed for irrelevance.–Econlib Ed.]
Richard Genz
Jun 9 2015 at 2:03pm
@ Harvey Cody
You write “the negative consequences of climate change are not [certain] and caution, if not skepticism, is fully warranted by all.”
The possibility that a particular house will burn down this year is not certain, so caution about buying insurance, if not skepticism, is warranted by all.
Does that make sense? No. See Russ Roberts and Nassim Taleb:
RR: “what is the precautionary principle and why is it important?
NT : Okay. There’s some water on the floor. Do you drink from it? Would you drink from it? No. Why do you not drink from water on the floor, if you are thirsty, you are very careful. But you have *no evidence* that it’s poisonous. Uh-huh. So you are making a *decision without evidence.* This is the exercise of the precautionary principle in your daily life. In other words, for things for which you don’t have evidence, you try to stay cautious until you accumulate the evidence; then you can pick the risk.” -Econtalk 1-19-15, emphasis added.
Congratulations to Soros, Steyer, and any other white-hat oligarch who cares to do battle w/ the fossil fuel complex.
Richie
Jun 9 2015 at 4:37pm
@Broadfoot,
My apologies. Now I see that you were correcting his 4 cents/gallon assumption, and correcting it to 35 cents/gallon. I misread your decimal and thought you were going with 3.5/cents per gallon.
I still think that a 35 cent/gallon tax is way too low to have any meaningful impact in gasoline usage in the USA. In the past decade, we have had price fluctuations of well over $1/gallon within 6 months.
Robert Swan
Jun 10 2015 at 9:01pm
Late to the party as usual but I’ll comment anyway. I broadly agree with Harvey Cody’s comments; just a couple of other points.
It was a good discussion; refreshing to hear a less ardent believer discussing with a less ardent sceptic.
There are many technical weaknesses in the climate models, and in the temperature record (longer term). Fair enough not to explore these in depth in a discussion between economists, but they deserved more coverage than they got. They eat into the credibility of extreme claims.
Another way to evaluate credibility, psychological rather than technical, is to estimate what we might call the “Roberts ratio” (b:B bootleggers:Baptists). The number of climate advocates whose actions belie their words is impressive. E.g., the tiny proportion of advocates who advance nuclear power as a remedy.
For those invoking Taleb’s take on the precautionary principle, I don’t buy it. I commented more than enough on it in that thread.
Vangel
Jun 10 2015 at 10:04pm
@Robert Swan
Another way to evaluate credibility, psychological rather than technical, is to estimate what we might call the “Roberts ratio” (b:B bootleggers:Baptists).
This is not that simple to do. Most of the big oil and gas companies want a carbon tax. The tax would kill the shale producers (who have never been economic outside of tiny core areas in the better formations) but more importantly would make coal much more expensive to use. By increasing the price of gas they are hoping that their marginal fields would become useful and that recognition of reserves at the 6:1 BTU content ratio would hide the problem with reserve declines in conventional oil deposits.
Since governments want more revenues they are in favour of carbon taxes. So is the green movement and the alternative energy sector. Most scientists get paid to promote the government message so they are in favour. And if you look around you will find that even many supposedly small government, conservative politicians are also on board. Those in favour also include many consumer and industry groups, professional organizations, etc.
On the other side, those that are actively opposing the scam are few in number and have lost the funding war. They can’t get their message out very easily and are marginalized by people who claim that the science is settled even when the empirical evidence shows the exact opposite.
What this issue needs is honest and open debate. Sadly, we are not going to get it.
Robert Swan
Jun 11 2015 at 7:56pm
@Vangel
I was being a bit tongue in cheek with the b:B ratio. It’s subjective. All the same, you had no bother listing a handful of bootleggers and I’m confident b:B amongst the outspoken is much more than 1:1, perhaps 10:1. I think many have quietly made this judgement for themselves and so, despite (as you described) the very one-sided nature of the public discourse, polls show climate change trending ever lower in people’s priorities.
I agree that we aren’t going to see an honest and open debate. Such a debate would end pretty quickly with a “needs more work” verdict. The advocates are much happier continuing to berate doubters with “It’s basic physics” and such like. If it’s such basic physics, what’s the need for these sophisticated computer models? And what basic physics sees heat scurrying off to hide in the deep oceans?
A good opportunity for a popular W.B.Yeats quote:
Paul L
Jun 25 2015 at 10:36am
@Robert Swan
I’d like to make a few points in response to your comment:
I took offense at the sweeping characterization of those who are concerned and feel an urgency with regard to climate change.
As for the role of “basic physics”, you have it quite backwards; if you make a claim that defies basic physics you’d better have a compelling reason to back it up. Energy flux, heat capacity, atmospheric spectral transmittance are all basic physical concepts that you appear to dismiss. Physicists crave simplicity. Basic physics: energy cannot be created nor destroyed – you are, in effect, basing your skepticism on the opposite.
I am interested in the way you frame the debate. You refer to those who espouse no action on climate change as “doubters” when, in my view they are, more often than not, actually deniers. I see the former as healthy objective skeptics and the latter as those with a deeply held conviction that is threatened. (The book, “Merchants of Doubt” addresses this.) It is clear to me that if climate change is real, the only solution is a collective one. This is so abhorrent to some, that even basic physics must take a back seat.
groweg
Jun 26 2015 at 10:37am
Weitzman does not produce any evidence CO2 can produce harmful warming. Upending our energy economy without any evidence that CO2 can cause harmful warming is ridiculous. The evidence against CO 2 determining climate is massive. Challenge to Weitzman or anyone else: Spend a few hours on the information below and then assess the likelihood of a “Black Swan” from CO 2 induced climate change.
Nir Shaviv (Hebrew University of Jerusalem)
http://www.sciencebits.com/Munich-2012
Henrick Svensmark’s theory (Danish National Space Institute)
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=n1qGOUIRac0
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=gTqBrML4nsc
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=yv06IyygoUs
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=y87vLJrh2AY
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=6pRmbBsdhNE
Summaries of recent results on Svensmark’s theory:
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2013/09/04/svensmarks-cosmic-ray-theory-of-clouds-and-global-warming-looks-to-be-confirmed/
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2014/04/10/more-support-for-svensmarks-cosmic-ray-modulation-of-earths-climate-hypothesis/
Willie Soon (Harvard – Smithsonian Center for Astrophysics) and David Legates (University of Delaware):
http://itsrainmakingtime.com/drs-willie-soon-david-legates-true-inquiry-into-climate-weather/
Richard Lindzen (MIT)
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ThVoO39cFT8
Global warming models have failed:
http://landshape.org/enm/scientific-method-meets-global-warming/
Roy Spencer (U. of Alabama and NASA), Global warming 101:
http://www.drroyspencer.com/global-warming-101/
Below is a blog site, scroll down to read “Will the solar doldrums of the coming decades lead to cooling? A look at the latest scientific publications:
http://notrickszone.com/
Disproving Al Gore on the relationship between CO2 and temperature
http://iceagenow.info/2014/05/video-great-global-warming-swindle-excerpt/
http://notrickszone.com/2014/06/20/epica-ice-core-analysis-nowhere-do-we-see-temperature-lagging-co2/
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2009/01/30/co2-temperatures-and-ice-ages/
No correlation of ice ages and Co2 levels
http://home.comcast.net/~pdrallos131681/CO2/co2.html
Manipulated data
http://www.telegraph.co.uk/earth/environment/10916086/The-scandal-of-fiddled-global-warming-data.html
absorption
http://nov79.com/gbwm/prmr.html
Global sea ice levels (combined Arctic and Antarctic) are above average. Artic levels are close to normal and Antarctic ice levels are at record high levels.
Sea ice levels
http://wattsupwiththat.com/reference-pages/sea-ice-page/
Antarctic sea ice at record levels
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2014/05/12/antarctic-sea-ice-at-record-levels/
No global warming whatsoever since 1996 in satellite temperature records (the most accurate reading of atmospheric temperature changes)
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2014/04/28/sea-level-rise-slows-while-satellite-temperature-pause-dominates-measurement-record/
Talk by Richard Lindzen (MIT).
http://wattsupwiththat.com/2014/06/13/dr-richard-lindzens-talk-at-eike/#comments
http://stevengoddard.wordpress.com/2014/06/27/who-is-steven-goddard/
climate myths
http://landscapesandcycles.net/the-greatest-climate-myths-of-all—part-1-.html
http://landscapesandcycles.net/the-greatest-climate-myths-of-all—part-1-.html
costs
http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2014/jun/27/rohrabacher-presidential-snow-job-on-global-warmin/?page=all#pagebreak
Best global warming websites
http://wattsupwiththat.com/
http://notrickszone.com/
http://hockeyschtick.blogspot.com/
bogwood
Jun 27 2015 at 11:11am
My neighbor always asks “compared to what? ” In this context comparing problem of climate change with problem of resource depletion. Will the economic effects of fossil fuel depletion kick in before climate change becomes critical?
There is a less academic discussion on ourfiniteworld.com. There is a lot of resource available just not cheap enough to run the current complex economy. The fossil fuel “slaves” assisting productivity are demanding more and more “salary”. Most in the ground fossil fuel will stay there. Debt and supply change problems will dominate the climate issue. It is peakoil in a more nuanced form emphasizing the financial aspects rather than all geology.
I lean toward the complexity/resource problem as more immediate, but just finished Mark Buchanan’s book “Forecast” outlining financial threats even without peak resources.
Robert Swan
Jun 28 2015 at 10:48pm
@Paul L
I’m sorry that my remark offended you.
I don’t think this is the right forum to get into details, but the “basic physics” argument doesn’t wash with me. To keep it brief, I’ll just give an example of where some climate scientists show that they are willing to suspend a rule of basic physics.
For the last fifteen or so years the mean measured surface temperature has been pretty static, diverging from the climate models. Some climate scientists have explained this by saying that the heat is still building up, being stored in the deep oceans. Evidently they decided that the basic physics of convection could be outranked by other factors.
In a nutshell, complexity can trump basic physics any day of the week. As you put it yourself “Physicists crave simplicity”. Would this not make weather (and therefore climate) something a physicist would stay well away from?
As to your last paragraph, I don’t see much value in throwing around epithets. Call me a denier if it pleases you, but I don’t deny that climates change. What I do deny is that the mechanisms of climate are understood. As for the climate models, I’m not alone; the real world looks like it too denies their accuracy.
Comments are closed.